Air Pollution Abatement Strategies
ABATE Case
About TED Categories and Clusters
CASE NUMBER: 299 CASE MNEMONIC: ABATE CASE NAME: Air Pollution and Abatement Strategies
A. IDENTIFICATION
1. The Issue
Air pollution is a major global problem. It exacerbates existing health problems, produces health problems where there otherwise would not be any and, in severe cases, causes death. Air pollution is also responsible for a wide variety of environmental problems including damaged forests and crops, acid deposition (acid rain) and widespread destruction of acid sensitive aquatic environments and organisms. All these impacts entail significant economic costs. As these costs become widely known, pollution abatement becomes increasingly important. There are a number of different pollution abatement techniques available to polluting industries as well as a number of different strategies to encourage industry to implement those techniques. The four strategies surveyed in this study include direct regulation, taxation, facilitation of private litigation, and a system of tradeable pollution permits.
2. DESCRIPTION
Air pollution is not a recent phenomena. Contamination of the atmosphere has been a constant side effect of industrialization. The severity of air pollution and the public's acute awareness of it, however, is relatively recent. As industrialization has taken on a global dimension since the end of World War II, so has pollution. Although severe occurrences like the deadly 1952 London "black fog" are relatively rare, they have served to highlight the need for pollution abatement
Anthropogenic (man made) air pollution comes from many sources, can have numerous components including various sulfurous oxides (SOx), nitrous oxides (NOx), ozone, hydrocarbons, Cloroflouro-carbons (CFCs), and heavy metals and is the subject of this case study. Specific concentrations and composition of pollutants is tremendously location specific and would be an appropriate component of a case study on a particular industry or region. Naturally occurring pollution, such as forest fires and volcanic eruptions, can also cause significant deterioration in air quality but cannot be controlled or mitigated by policy action and are therefore outside the scope of this study.
Atmospheric pollution released from readily identifiable sources is referred to as primary pollution while pollutants that occur as a result of a chemical reaction with or in the atmosphere are secondary pollutants. The categories of primary pollution sources are mobile or stationary, combustion or non-combustion, area or point sources, direct or indirect. Mobile sources include automobiles, trains, and airplanes. A point source is a stationary source whose emissions have significant impact on air quality while an area source is one which is not a significant polluter by itself but contributes to air pollution as part of a group of relatively small polluters. <1>
Not all forms of air pollution can be accounted for by "traditional" gaseous and particulate matter. Non-traditional forms of air pollution include noise, odor, heat, ionizing radiation, and electromagnetic fields. These forms of pollution are mentioned for the sake of thoroughness but will not be examined in this study. Although internal combustion engines (particularly two stroke and diesel engines which are prevalent in the developing world and in former East Bloc countries) are the most publicly visible sources of pollution, large quantities of pollutants are by-products of fossil-fuel burning industries - particularly coal fired power plants and metal smelters. This case study will examine the pollution effects of and abatement strategies for fixed point source polluters such as power plants and metal smelters. The Costs of Pollution
Air pollution has been linked to many negative impacts on human health and on the health of the environment. In addition to the notorious episodes such as the London "black fog" of 1952 that killed thousands, pollution causes serious, ongoing general health hazards of a less conspicuous, but no less dangerous kind. Pollu- tion has also been identified as a causal factor in building deterioration, lowered visibility, fish kills, global warming, and widespread tree and plant damage, all of which have serious economic consequences.
The costs of various forms of pollution abatement are relatively easy to calculate. Air "scrubbers" that reduce particulate matter and other toxic output and higher quality coal can be specifically priced out and their effects can be accurately projected. The costs of non-abatement - continued pollution - are much more difficult to calculate and are subject to a far higher degree of uncertainty. Although less certain than pollution abatement pricing, evidence on the real cost of pollution is growing stronger and gaining wider acceptance among the public and in government. Health Costs
The most severe episodes of air pollution have caused significant loss of life. Belgium's Meuse Valley was the sight of 60 air pollution related deaths in 1930. Donora, Pennsylvania was the scene of 20 deaths in 1948. The infamous London "black fog" claimed approximately 4000 lives in 1952 and has been linked to increased mortality during "fogs" dating back as far as 1873. In these cases a persistent thermal inversion prevented atmospheric dispersion resulting in excessively high pollution levels from coal fired home furnaces (London) or from heavy industry (Meuse and Donora). <2>
Widespread illness has also been linked to pollution including half of the 14,000 people in the affected area of the afore- mentioned Donora, Pennsylvania incident. <3> In the United States, 150 million people live in regions with unfit air according to the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). Greater Athens experiences a sixfold increase in the number of deaths on heavy pollution days; Hungary concluded that every 17th death and every 24th disability is the result of air pollution; and in Bombay, India, breathing the air is equivalent to smoking 10 cigarettes a day. <4> Some researchers believe the combination of sulfur dioxide and water in the air allow people to breathe toxic metals and gasses deep into their lungs causing as many as 50,000 deaths in the Untied States every year - 2 percent of annual mortality. <5>
These examples may represent extreme cases. Nonetheless, they clearly demonstrate to some degree the deleterious health effects of air pollution. Exposure to levels of air pollution that do not cause immediate acute illness or death are more difficult to assess. However, ambient air pollution has been implicated as a causal factor in: 1. chronic respiratory and cardiovascular disease 2. alteration of body functions such as lung ventilation and oxygen transport 3. reduced work and athletic performance 4. sensory irritation of the eyes, nose, and throat 5. aggravation of existing disease such as asthma. Air pollution may also result in the storage of harmful substances in the body. <6> (See Godish, Chapter 5, and Webster, Table 3 for a detailed analysis of the health effects of pollution.) One study determined that every ton of sulfur dioxide emitted into the atmosphere causes over $3,000 of health-related damage in affected communities which translates into a cost of $25 billion for the emissions from midwestern coal-fired power plants alone. <7> Atmospheric pollutants also produce indirect health hazards. Acid "rain" (discussed in more detail below) makes dangerous metals like aluminum, cadmium, lead, and mercury more soluble. These metals can be leached from soils and lake sediments into aquatic environments where they contaminate water supplies and edible fish. Acidic water can also dissolve toxic metals from municipal and home water systems thereby poisoning drinking water. <8>
Environmental Costs
While human health is the most important impact of pollution, the environmental impact is significant as well. Much of the directly observable environmental impact is the result of acid (sulfuric and nitric) deposition - more commonly known as "acid rain." Pollutants can effect the frequency and quantity of precipitation as well as the chemical content of raindrops and other forms of acid deposition such as snow, frost, dew, and fog. Acid can be deposited in dry conditions on ground surfaces as well. Hence the term "acid deposition" is more accurately descriptive of the overall phenomena.
Acid deposition is created in the atmosphere by chemical reactions of sulfur dioxide (SO2) or nitrogen oxides (NOx). In the late 1960s, Swedish ecologists first connected acidity of rainfall in affected watersheds with species composition in a number of lakes. The problem was not recognized in North America until the mid-1970s <9> when investigations concluded that acid deposition was indeed acidifying water and killing aquatic organisms. <10>
The precursors of acid deposition, sulfur and nitrogen oxides, are emitted from fossil-fuel-fired power plants, industrial boilers, metal smelters, and automobiles. Acid deposition in the United States is due primarily to sulfuric (65%) and nitric (30%) acids and approximately 60-70% of the SOx emissions are reported to be associated with large electric power plants which burn high- sulfur coal. <11>
Acidification is a worldwide problem. In addition to the highly publicized acidification cases in North America, particularly the American northeast and eastern Canada, much of Europe, Africa, Asia and South America are also acid sensitive.
In some regions, biologists have extrapolated experimental findings to conclude that more than half the sensitive species such as mollusks, leeches, and crustaceans have been eliminated in acidified areas. <12> Acidification may also reduce total phytoplankton biomass while increasing certain algae species. In severely acidified lakes, these algae species cover all surfaces with thick mat (algae blooms) which inhibits the life and feeding cycles of other aquatic organisms, contributing to the decrease in species diversity. Strong acidity leads to binding of nutrient ions to minerals, preventing their absorption by phytoplankton -the primary component of the food chain. <13> Clearly, acidification has drastic consequences on acidified watersheds.
In addition to this severe disruption of the food chain and the ensuing ecological problems, acidification is more detrimental to smaller and younger fish due to their large body and gill surface per unit weight. Fish mortality is also caused by the toxic effects of aluminum ions and heavy metals such as mercury which can be mobilized from lake sediments through acidification. <14> Some research suggests that coastal waters are at risk as well as fresh water sources.
Vegetation is also subject to damage destruction from acid deposition. Particularly severe damage is associated with the high concentration of SO2 and heavy metal emissions from primary metal smelters. <15> Forest damage due to acid deposition first became evident in West Germany where the first survey (1982) indicated that 8 percent of German forest were damaged. The following year, 34 percent were surveyed as damaged with the peak of 54 percent occurring in 1986. The percentage has decreased slightly (52 percent in 1988) but since dead trees are not included in the survey, lower percentages do not necessarily constitute an improvement. <16>
In addition to the direct damage from acid deposition, the mixture of acid deposition, ozone, and toxic metals makes vegetation more vulnerable to naturally occurring stresses such as drought, temperature extremes, and blight. European surveys have concluded that 50 million hectares - 35 percent of Europe's forested area - have been damaged. <17>
The economic costs of such widespread damage are equally large. Poland projects that it will lost $1.5 billion by 1992 due to forest damage while Germany estimates that forest damage will cost the country $3 billion to $5 billion annually over the next 70 years. Additionally, crops are damaged by pollution (particularly ozone) and are estimated to represent economic losses in the United States of $5.4 billion per year from reduced crop yields. <18> Pollution, particularly the acid derivatives of SO2 emission, corrode monuments and historical artifacts. T.N. Skoulikidis, a Greek expert on acid corrosion, estimates that pollution has caused more deterioration of Athenian monuments in the last 20-25 years than has occurred during the previous 2400 years. <19> Air pollution also effects paper and leather, significantly reducing their usable life span. Fabrics and textile dyes are also adversely affected by air pollution. Other problems include metal corrosion, odor pollution, and rubber deterioration.
All of pollution's negative impacts have significant economic effects - both direct and indirect. Health costs, already staggering in the United States, are placed in greater demand by pollution related illnesses and exacerbations of existing medical problems. Damaged trees actually cost money in the form of lost revenue in addition to tourism decline in heavily impacted areas. Regions impacted by pollution odor experience declines in property value. Farmers experience reductions in crop yield driving up produce prices. Clothes and paper products deteriorate faster and require more frequent washing which also hastens their deterioration and contributes to higher demand for textiles. The fishing and wilderness tourism industry is clearly a big loser and we all lose a degree of visibility that threatens our enjoyment of natural wonders like the Grand Canyon. (See TED case: GRAND) Given all these costs, it is no surprise that the public and governments are accelerating their search for ways to reduce toxic emissions.
Pollution Abatement Strategies
Given the need to reduce pollution, the question becomes one of finding the most effective pollution abatement techniques and the best way to implement them. This effort compounded by the global nature of the problem and transboundary impacts of particular pollution sources. Several different abatement strategies have been proposed including different forms of taxation, direct regulation and monitoring, the allowance of private litigation on environmental issues, and tradeable pollution "permits."
The damage and attendant costs of air pollution are becoming increasingly evident and increasingly large. On the other side of the coin, is the dependence of industrialized economies on fossil- fuel based industrial, power, and transportation systems. With the exception of the United Arab Emirates, Europe and North America are clearly the largest producers of energy on a per capita basis <20> and have the highest concentration of automobiles.
There is clearly an economic expense attached to pollution abatement measures. The conflicting interests in the pollution debate make the issue a political one. Consequently, potential pollution abatement strategies must not only be economically feasible and effective at reducing pollution, they must also be politically feasible AND sustainable over time. Developing an approach that meets all of these requirements is a world class challenge.
Emission Reduction Techniques
Pollution abatement technology is becoming big business. European pollution abatement generate $50 billion a year <21> while US firms spent nearly $100 billion on pollution control in 1990 and are expected to spend as much as $150 billion by the year 2000. <22> It has also become a major political issue in many regions, most notably between the United States and Canada and within the European Community. While science and industry search for more cost-effective solutions, it would be useful to note currently available methods of pollution control.
The most common method of removing particulate matter from power plant emission has been the use of electrostatic and baghouse filters. This technology is required in most OECD countries. While this technology reduces direct particulate emission by as much as 99.5 percent, it does not prevent gaseous emissions or prevent them from forming acidic particles upon reaction with outside elements. <23>
Sulfur dioxide emission is most commonly controlled through flue-gas desulfurization (FGD) devices known as "scrubbers" which can remove up to 95 percent of SO2 emissions. This technology is becoming more widespread but its application is still far from universal, especially in the United States where it is projected that by the year 2000 only 30 percent of American power plants will have installed "scrubbers." <24>
Controlling nitrogen oxides (NO2) emissions has been pursued through several different techniques. A simple modification of its combustion process has resulted in 30-50 percent decreases in NO2 output. Selective catalytic reduction (SCR) can reduce emission by 80-90 percent but is far more expensive to implement. This tech- nology is likely to be more widely implemented in the future. <25>
"Clean coal" (see TED case: CHINCOAL) technologies are also under development which lower SO2 and NOx emission while providing more efficient combustion. This technique employs fluidized bed combustion technology which burns crushed coal on a bed of limestone suspended by injected air or the integrated gasification- combined cycle which turns coal into a gas to power a turbine and uses excess heat from that process to power a second turbine. <26>
Another measure that industry can use to reduce emission is to use lower-sulfur coal. While this is technically easy to implement, there are large political and economic ramifications for local coal producers who are frequently subsidized, protected, or otherwise guaranteed a market in many American states. <27> All these technologies are steps in the right direction. We must also note that many of them produce their own environmental hazards. Scrubbers, for instance, produce scrubber ash, a hazardous waste. Furthermore, these technologies do not reduce carbon dioxide emissions and do not reduce industry's impact on the problem of global warming. <28>
Pollution Abatement Implementation Strategies
Balancing the needs of polluters (who provide many products upon which industrial societies depend) with the public's need for clean air calls for thoughtful policy instruments that take the needs of all sides into account - not the least of which is the political sustainability of any particular policy instrument over time. Four broad classes of policy instruments have been proposed to reduce pollution: 1. direct regulation 2. taxation 3. provision of framework for private litigation 4. creation of a market of tradeable pollution "permits" These four strategies are not necessarily mutually exclusive although there are positive and negative aspects of each which must be considered when formulating effective policy.
Direct Regulation has been a mainstay of national policy instruments. Regulation provides transparency and certainty, crucial factors for business decision making. Transparency provides interested parties with specific details on permissible and impermissible actions. Certainty is partially a function of effective enforcement including efficient monitoring and reliable prosecution/punishment provisions.
However, the costs of creating, administering, and enforcing regulations (including all the small print) can be an arduous task even at the national level. The job takes on a vastly more complex and problematic dimension when the international arena is the target community. Differences in national interests are compounded by different cultures, legal systems, and economies.
International enforcement would also be difficult. Without a world body to impartially enforce the regulations (few countries are willing to give up their sovereignty to an international organization), enforcement would be left up to national bureaucracies. The differences between the operations of such organizations would undermine the regulations since it would be effectively impossible for the regulations to be equally enforced in every country. <29> Nonetheless, international agreement and attempts at equivalent compliance are a major step above non- agreement and should be vigorously pursued.
Furthermore, regulations do not make allowances for local variations in conditions. This rigidity unduly punishes some and unduly rewards others all while creating a potentially hostile environment for new entries into the market that might employ more environmentally sound practices. <30>
Taxation of various pollutants, per ton of SO2 emitted for instance, is a second instrument for reducing toxic emissions. Taxes provide an incentive for polluters to reduce their emissions and provide revenue to continue administration of the tax and to promote other pollution abatement programs. Governments are also familiar with this instrument and would find easy to implement.
Taxation becomes a problem at the international level. Issues of which currency tax is to be paid in and exchange rate problems would abound. More importantly would be the international administration collecting the tax and how it would use the revenues therefrom. This would be a major sovereignty issue. <31>
The European Community has proposed a tax of $3 per barrel of oil to reduce carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions. This tax would be gradually raised to $10 a barrel by 2000. To avoid trade and competition inequities resulting from the tax, energy intensive industries with significant foreign trade interests would be exempt until competitor countries - Japan and the United States - adopt similar measures. <32>
Private Litigation facility is a third option. By allowing private concerns (extra-national as well national) to sue violators of international pollution agreements, regulatory costs would be minimized since enforcement would be provided - perhaps sporadically - through litigation by interested/injured parties. The ability of wealthy polluters to stall legal proceedings, the uncertainty of compliance with an international court and the sovereignty issue such a body raises are obvious disadvantages to this system. It should be noted, however, that international law relating to oil spills at sea and European transboundary pollution treaties have established some legal precedents upon which to base a greater role for private litigation. <33>
While private litigation may be insufficient to lower toxic emissions and improve air quality, it may prove to be a valuable addition to the other strategies by providing an additional compliance incentive for polluters.
Tradeable Permits are a market based approach to pollution abatement that combines financial incentives similar to taxation but requires substantially less regulatory oversight. Essentially, polluters are given/sold pollution permits (see TED case CLEAN), each of which allows a certain amount of a particular pollutant such as one ton of SO2, according to a pre-calculated formula. The total number of permits distributed equals the total emissions target thereby establishing a maximum pollution level. This total emission threshold would be lowered over time.
The world's first example of a tradeable permit system was launched in 1993. The Chicago Board of Trade held the first auction of tradeable permits for SO2 emissions on March 29, 1993 and the second on March 28, 1994. The marginal interest in these events suggest that market trading will not be a significant factor in utilities' short term efforts to comply with Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments. The lack of response may also result from industry's unfamiliarity with the market concept and relevant pricing strategies. Also, an unknown number or permits have been privately traded. <34> Additionally, the instigation of tradeable permits it sufficiently recent that it is too early to determine the full range of its impact.
The heart of the system would be the market for the pollution permits in which permits could be freely traded. The result would be that polluters that could most easily/economically lower emissions would do so and sell their unused permits to others. Since trading is an open market, environmental interests could purchase the permits as easily as other polluters, driving up the price and therefore the incentive to reduce emissions. The price would also increase over time as the cap on total emissions was reduced. <35>
This system would be very inexpensive for the government to operate and also allow extra time - at a price - for those polluters that need to postpone adoption of costly emission reduction procedures and equipment.
Since tradeable permits do not involve taxation per se, they are relatively easy to sustain politically. They also provide real (and increasing) incentives to lower emissions. By structuring the costs of permits less than fines for non-compliance, they become an attractive option, theoretically reducing detailed oversight requirements.
A system of tradeable permits also has some drawbacks. Heavy polluters may find it economical to purchase extra permits and produce even more pollution that will predominantly affect another state/country. This problem could be addressed through the initial permit allocation process. The United States in particular favors "grandfather" permits that allocate permits on the basis of previous emission output. <36> In effect, the more pollution produced in the past, the more permits that industry is entitled to in the present and in the future. Other options could be allocating permits on a per unit population basis or by reducing the price of permits for industries that produce less pollution per kilowatt hour of energy produced.
Lastly, there is a very basic concern, especially among environmentalists, over essential property rights. By allowing a permit to pollute, polluting industries are effectively given property rights to air resources - rights that are withheld from private citizens who also are entitled to use of the air. It also legitimates the polluter's "right to pollute" at the expense of the public's right to enjoy a pollution free environment. <37>
Conclusion
At the present time, there seems to be no "ideal" solution to the pollution problem that simultaneously addresses the needs of polluters, the public, and the politicians. Direct regulation, taxation, a greater role for private litigation, and tradeable permits all have advantages and disadvantages. For the immediate future, the system of tradeable credits appears to be the most feasible solution. It infringes least upon the sovereignty issue, provides real economic incentives to promote pollution abatement, and is the least costly to operate.
Direct regulation, private litigation, and taxation would take a tremendous amount of coordination. While feasible at the national and sub-national level, initiation of such measures in an international context takes on nearly insurmountable problems. It will be very difficult to achieve consensus among even a majority nations, let alone near unanimity. Any provision that all governments would find acceptable are highly likely to be effective at actually reducing emissions. The more governments that are involved, the more diluted the agreement is likely to be. Additionally, governments have widely disparate domestic political situations and constituencies as well as widely diverging objectives in the international arena.
Tradeable permits would certainly have to overcome these same problems. However, their cost efficient and free market nature make them much more palatable. Many industrialized countries, notably the United States and the European Union are already considering or implementing such measures. The global availability of such permits could drive the price of such permits down relative to smaller national or regional permit systems making the largest polluters - and thus potential opponents - also interested in lobbying for a global permit system. Many Third World nations might also be willing to join a global system of tradable pollution permits. Since most Third World countries pollute far less than the industrialized nations, a system of tradeable permits would effectively become a resource transfer between "North" and "South" that would increase available development resources which would be highly welcome during the current decline in aid allocations. Much of the current literature barely touches or ignores several other alternatives that would complement all of these measures. Greater education, particularly combined with the availability of information regarding polluter's emission levels, about pollution would promote awareness and greater citizen oversight of pollution sources. As public awareness increases, its interest in environmentally sound products increases leading to competitive advantage for firms able to advertise their goods as environmentally friendly as in the proposed European eco-labeling program. <38>
While this paper my not constitute a "case study" per se, its content provides a useful context for future work on air pollution. The "case" of this paper addresses the currently available strategies for reducing air pollution. Other studies can concentrate on specifics without reiterating the options for such reduction. It also provides valuable background reference material for those interested in air pollution and its effects. Similar studies on the scope of alternatives regarding water pollution (surface and ground water, fresh and salt), ground pollution (organic and toxic, surface longevity and seepage to water table), and mobile sources of air pollution would be useful as well. Future studies may find it useful to compare and contrast TED cases at levels other than the obvious comparisons such as geography, standing, habitat, etc. readily offered by the TED coding format. One level that comes from this study is a comparison of strategies used in various locations/countries and the consequences and costs of implementation. Other comparisons could be between regulatory structures such as similar taxation plans, between comparable climatic air regions with similar polluter profiles and densities, public awareness and response to similar circumstances, policy response and enforcement, industry response to regulation and public articulation. Other interesting comparisons would involve the transparency of regulation, public availability of pollution data, and the economics and politics involved in creating and enforcing regulation.
Other cases, more akin to policy recommendations, could argue for establishing particular abatement strategies in particular locations and within existing political contexts since pollution solutions are not equally feasible in a political sense across countries or regions (or even localities). Policy recommendation cases could also involve a search for sponsors and prospective allies that would support the recommendation and identification of those groups most likely to oppose it and the opponent's avenues of contesting the recommendation. Another interesting case would be to examine the environmental impact of pollution abatement equip- ment manufacturing.
3. Related Cases
Go to CLEAN Go to CO2TRADE Go to CHINCOAL Go to ECCARBON Go to ECCO2 Go to MONTREAL Go to CFCTRADE Go to SULFUR Go to GRAND Go to CHILEAIR Go to JAPANAIR Go to KORPOLL Go to POLWASTE
Keyword Clusters
(1): Trade Product = MANY (2): Bio-geography = GLOBAL (3): Environmental Problem = Air Pollution [POLA]
4. Draft author: David Field
B. LEGAL Filters
5. Discourse and Status: [DIS]agree and [ALLEGE]
6. Forum and Scope: [GLOBAL] and [MULTI]
7. Decision Breadth: 175+
8. Legal Standing: SUBLAW
Although the 1992 Rio de Janeiro (Earth) Summit addressed issues of pollution, few substantive global agreements were reached. The United States has some of the most stringent internal laws on mobile pollution sources (mostly automobiles) and has made progress on industrial pollution through the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990. NAFTA also attempts to address issues of transboundary pollution. The EC is working to set up a European environmental agency that will help unify environmental regulation and compliance and probably represents the most ambitious effort to date to draft multi-national regional environmental regulations. C.
C. GEOGRAPHIC Clusters
9. Geographic Domain
a. Geographic Domain: GLOBAL b. Geographic Impact: GLOBAL b. Geographic Site: GLOBAL
Air pollution freely crosses political boundaries making it an issue of multi-national importance. Most of the pollution problem experienced by Norway originates in Germany and Central Europe. Sweden, Poland, the Baltic States and Belarus are seriously impacted by pollution from Ukraine, most notably radiation from the Cherynobl nuclear power plant. Not all countries are equally affected by pollution, equal producers of pollution, or equally concerned about the problem. Nonetheless, the transboundary nature of air pollution makes it a problem of global dimensions.
10. Sub-National Factors YES
11. Type of Habitat: MANY
D. TRADE Clusters
12. Type of Measure: MANY
13. Direct vs. Indirect Impacts: BOTH
Air pollution causes many direct impacts on health (respiratory problems) and on the environment (cost to timber industry) as well as numerous indirect effects such as decreased tourism, food chain disruption, higher lumber prices, and environmental activism.
14. Relation of Measure to Environmental Impact
a. Directly related: YES MANY b. Indirectly related: YES MANY c. Not Related: YES RETALiation d. Process Related: YES MANY
15. Trade Product Identification: MANY
16. Economic Data
Industry output (pollution abatement) United States - $100 billion European Community - $50 billion
These figures only include funds spent directly on pollution abatement equipment/processes and do not include cost of regulation enforcement or other material inputs such as coal or oil. Health Costs (air pollution caused)
United States (areas impacted by coal-burning midwest plants) $25 billion per year. United States - 50,000 deaths per year.
This category is very difficult to measure accurately and has therefore been subject to a great deal of debate. It is increasingly evident that pollution does have a negative influence on health so the debate is currently centered on how much influence and no longer on whether there are harmful effects or not.
Environmental Costs United States - $5.4 billion per year crop reduction Poland - $1.5 billion per year lost timber Germany - $3 - $5 billion per year lost timber
It should also be noted that dollar losses simply reflect cost of not harvesting damaged trees and as such only represent the value of trees used as commodity. The figures do not represent all damaged trees and do not reflect the myriad other effects that stem from such damage such as higher timber prices, higher construction prices, fewer timber industry workers, higher fire threat to damaged forests, and reduced tourism.
17. Impact of Measure on Trade Competitiveness: LOW
This impact status is likely to increase. As more environmental agreements are reached, nationally, regionally, and globally, coordination of regulations will become increasingly important because of the transboundary nature of the problem. The likely result will be the imposition of overt tariffs for goods produced in countries without compatible environmental regulation as well as non-tariff barriers on particular non-complying products and services.
18. Industry Sector: MANY
The combination of direct and indirect effects of pollution from numerous sources and industries on an even greater array of health concerns, environments, and products defies any attempt to limit air pollution to one sector.
19. Exporter and Importer: MANY
E. ENVIRONMENT Clusters
20. Environmental Problem Type: MANY
21. Species Information
22. Impact and Effect: HIGH and MANY
23. Urgency and Lifetime: MEDIUM and 100s of years
24. Substitutes: NA
F. OTHER Factors
25. Culture: NO
26. Trans-border: YES
27. Rights: YES
The right to clean air has not been granted by specific statute. At some point, people's right to life is terminally infringed upon by pollution. At that point, the right to clean air is a human right. 28. Relevant Literature
Bertram, Geoffrey. "Tradeable Emission Permits and the Control of Greenhouse Gases." The Journal of Development Studies 28/3 (April 1992): 423-446. Bryner, Gary C. Blue Skies, Green Politics: The Clean Air Act of 1990. Washington DC: Congressional Quarterly Press, 1993. Godish, Thad. Air Quality, second edition. Chelsea, Michigan: Lewis Publishers, Inc., 1991. Koutstaal, Paul and Nentjes, Andries. "Tradable Carbon Permits in Europe: Feasibility and Comparison with Taxes." Journal of Common Market Studies 33/2 (June 1995): 219-233. Mostaghel, Deborah M. "State Reactions to the Trading of Emissions Allowances Under Title IV of the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990." Boston College Environmental Affairs Law Review 22/2 (Winter 1995): 201-224. Rehbinder, Eckard and Stewart, Richard. Environmental Protection Policy, Volume 2. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, 1985. Vial, Catherine. "Why EC Environmental Policy Will Affect American Business." Business America (March 8, 1993): 24-27. Webster, David B. "The Free Market for Clean Air." Business and Society Review (Summer 1994): 34-37. World Resources Institute. World Resources 1994-95. New York: Oxford University Press, 1994. World Watch Institute. "Cleaning the Air: A Global Agenda." World Watch Paper #94 (January 1994): 5-53. Related TED cases
References
<1> Thad Godish. Air Quality (Chelsea, Michigan: Lewis Publishers, 1991), 26-27. <2> Ibid, 131. <3> Ibid, 131. <4> World Watch Institute. Cleaning the Air: A Global Agenda (World Watch Paper #94) (New York: W.W. Norton, 1994) 5. <5> Ibid, 12. <6> Godish. op.cit. 132. <7> David B. Webster, "The Free Market for Clean Air," Business and Society Review (Summer 1994), 34-35. <8> World Watch Institute. op cit, 12. <9> Godish. op. cit. 104. <10> World Watch Institute. op cit, 17. <11> Godish. op. cit. 104-105. <12> World Watch Institute. op cit, 18-19. <13> Godish. op. cit. 107-108. <14> Ibid, 107. <15> Ibid, 173. <16> World Watch Institute. op cit, 19. <17> Ibid, 20. <18> Ibid, 22. <19> Ibid, 23. <20> World Resources Institute. World Resources 1994-95 (NY: Oxford University Press): Table 21.2, 334-335. <21> Catherine Vial. "Why EC Environmental Policy Will Affect American Business," Business America (March 8, 1993), 27. <22> Gary C. Bryner. Blue Skies, Green Politics: The Clean Air Act of 1990 (Washington DC: Congressional Quarterly): 9. <23> World Watch Institute. op cit, 25. <24> Ibid, 25. <25> Ibid, 26. <26> Ibid, 26. <27> Bryner. op. cit. 69. <28> World Watch Institute, op. cit. 26. <29> Geoffrey Bertram. "Tradeable Emission Permits and the Control of Greenhouse Gases," The Journal of Development Studies (April 1992): 431-432. <30> Bryner. op. cit. 21. <31> Bertram. op. cit. 433. <32> Vial. op. cit. 24-25. <33> Bertram. op. cit. 434-435. <34> Deborah M. Mostaghel. "State Reactions to the Trading of Emissions Allowances Under Title IV of the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990," Boston College Environmental Affairs Law Review (Winter 1995): 202-203. <35> Ibid, 207. <36> Paul Koutstaal and Andries Nentjes. "Tradable Carbon Permits in Europe: Feasibility and Comparison with Taxes," Journal of Common Market Studies (June 1995): 224-225. <37> Bertram. op. cit. 436. <38> Vial. op. cit. 24.
Go to Super Page
Go to TED OTHER Cases
Last revised: April 30, 1996
|